National Academies Press: OpenBook

Deterrence and the Death Penalty (2012)

Chapter: 3 determining the deterrent effect of capital punishment: key issues.

Determining the Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: Key Issues

M any people have strongly held views on the deterrent effect of the death penalty. To some a deterrent effect is self-evident—who would not at least take pause before committing murder when the potential consequence may be forfeiting one’s own life? To others it is equally self-evident that there is no deterrent effect due to the rarity of the imposition of the death penalty and the emotionally charged circumstances of most murders. Both views may have some merit, as the deterrent effect of the death penalty may vary across persons and circumstances. This chapter provides an overview of the difficulties of empirical analysis of the potential deterrent effect. The difficulties arise both from conceptual issues about how the death penalty might deter and from statistical issues that must be successfully overcome to measure the size of that effect, if any.

To argue for the deterrent effect of the death penalty in such ways as “because the death penalty increases the price of murder, there will be less of it” is to gloss over critical elements of understanding how it might work. The magnitude of the deterrent effect of the death penalty, including the possibility of no effect, will depend both on the scope of the legal authority for its use and on the way that legal authority is actually administered. It might also depend on such factors as the publicity given to executions, which are beyond the direct control of the criminal justice system.

One reflection of this complexity is that research on the deterrent effect of capital punishment in the post- Gregg era has itself examined diverse issues. Some studies have attempted to assess whether the legal status of capital punishment is related to the homicide rate. And some of these studies have addressed whether statewide homicide rates are associated with

whether capital punishment is a legally permissible sanction. Other studies have examined whether homicide rates are associated with moratoriums on executions ordered by governors or courts. There is also a distinct set of studies that have examined whether the frequency of and publicity given to actual executions are related to homicide rates. One part of this research has examined whether execution events seem to affect homicide rates; another part has examined whether homicide rates are associated with various measures of the probability of being executed for homicide.

Our overview of key challenges to making an empirical assessment of the effect of capital punishment on homicide rates is necessarily selective. There is an enormous research literature on the mechanisms by which legal sanctions, of which the death penalty is but one, might affect crime rates. There is also a very large research literature on the econometric and statistical methods used to estimate the effect of the death penalty on homicide rates. We focus on those issues that are particularly important to the reviews and critiques of the panel and time-series literatures in Chapters 4 and 5 , respectively. These issues include data limitations, factors beyond the death penalty that contribute to large differences in murder rates across place and over time, possible feedback effects by which homicide rates might affect the administration of the death penalty, how sanction risks are perceived, and the concept of a sanction regime.

There is also a literature that examines the argument that executions may actually exacerbate homicide rates through a brutalization effect. This argument has been studied using the same statistical tools as deterrence, although the mechanism being studied is different. With one exception, all of these are time-series studies, and we review them in Chapter 5 .

CONCEPTS OF DETERRENCE

Going back at least 200 years to the legal philosophers Cesare Beccaria in Italy and Jeremy Bentham in England, scholars have speculated on the deterrent effect of official sanctions. At its most basic level, deterrence is typically understood as operating within a theory of choice in which would-be offenders balance the benefits and costs of crime. In the context of murder, the benefits may be tangible, such as pecuniary gain or silencing a potential witness, but they may also involve intangibles, such as defending one’s honor, expressing outrage, demonstrating dominance, or simply seeking thrills. The potential costs of crime are comparably varied. Crime can entail personal risk if the victim resists (see, e.g., Cook, 1986). It may also invoke pangs of conscience or shame (see, e.g., Braithwaite, 1989).

In this report we are mainly concerned with the response of would-be offenders to the sanction costs that may result from the commission of murder. Such sanction costs will typically include lengthy imprisonment. Properly

understood, the relevant question regarding the deterrent effect of capital punishment is the differential or marginal deterrent effect of execution over the deterrent effect of other available or commonly used penalties. We emphasize “differential” because it is important to recognize that the alternative to capital punishment is not no punishment or a minor punishment such as probation. Instead, it is a lengthy prison sentence—often life without the possibility of parole.

The theory of deterrence is predicated on the idea that if state-imposed sanction costs are sufficiently severe, certain, and swift, criminal activity will be discouraged. Concerning the severity dimension, a necessary condition for state-sanctioned executions to deter crime is that, at least for some, capital punishment is deemed an even worse fate than the possibility of a lifetime of imprisonment. 1 Severity alone, however, cannot deter. There must also be some possibility that the sanction will be incurred if the crime is committed. For that to happen, the offender must be apprehended, charged, successfully prosecuted, and sentenced by the judiciary. As discussed in Chapter 2 , none of these successive stages in processing through the criminal justice system is certain. Thus, another key concept in deterrence theory is the certainty of punishment. Many of the studies of the deterrent effect of capital punishment attempt to estimate whether homicide rates seem to be affected by variation in various measures of the likelihood of execution beyond the likelihood of apprehension and conviction.

Across the social science disciplines, the concepts of certainty and severity have been made operational in deterrence research in very different ways. In Becker’s (1968) seminal economic formulation of criminal decision making, individual perceptions of certainty and severity are assumed to correspond to reality. The decision to commit a crime is also assumed to correspond with a precisely formulated set of axioms that define rational decision making. In contrast, among criminologists, models of criminal decision making are less mathematically formalized and place great emphasis on the role of perceptions. These models also explicitly acknowledge that perceptions of certainty and severity may diverge substantially from reality and are probably heavily influenced by experience with the criminal justice system (Cook, 1980; Nagin, 1998). More recent theorizing about criminal decision making also incorporates insights from behavioral economics on biases in risk perceptions to better model the linkage between sanction risk perceptions and reality (Durlauf and Nagin, 2011; Kleiman, 2009; Pogarsky, 2009). For example, prospect

__________________

1 Another way sanctions may prevent crime is by making it physically impossible for the offender to commit another crime. Execution achieves this end by the death of the offender. Note, however, that a death sentence will not, on the margin, be more effective in preventing crime (outside a prison) than the incapacitation that accompanies a sentence of life imprisonment without parole.

theory (Kahneman and Tversky, 1979) predicts that low probability events, such as execution, are either overweighted compared to models based on objective probabilities or not considered at all. While each of these perspectives on the deterrence process shares a common view that criminal decision making involves a balancing of costs and benefits, the conceptualization of how this balancing occurs varies greatly across theories. Most importantly for our purposes, the different models are based on different conceptions of how sanction risks are perceived and affect behavior.

A less studied dimension of the classical formulation of deterrence is the concept of celerity—the speed with which a sanction is imposed. In the case of the death penalty, celerity may be a particularly important dimension of the classical formulation. According to the Bureau of Justice Statistics (2010), the average time to execution for the executions that occurred between 1984 and 2009 was 10 years. This statistic, however, pertains only to the small minority of persons sentenced to death who have actually been executed. Only 15 percent of death sentences imposed since 1976 have been carried out. Thus, some individuals have been on death row for decades and indeed may die by other causes before they can be executed. Indeed, according to the Bureau of Justice Statistics (2010, Table 11) there have already been 416 such deaths (1973-2009) among death row inmates. For these offenders, their sentence was, in fact, equivalent to a life sentence.

The studies we review do little to reveal the underlying mechanisms that generate the associations that are estimated between the death penalty and the homicide rate. Indeed, it is possible that these associations reflect social processes that are distinct from deterrence in the narrow sense discussed above. For example, Andenæs (1974) and Packer (1968) speculate that independent of the sanctions prescribed in the criminal laws, the laws themselves may reduce the incidence of the prohibited acts by moral education and related social processes. Thus, providing the legal authority for the use of the death penalty for a special class of murders might prevent murders of that type by making clear that these types of murder are deemed particularly heinous. Alternatively, the brutalization hypothesis predicts the opposite effect.

Given these possible and unknown underlying mechanisms, in the remainder of this report we discuss empirical estimates of the effects of the death on the homicide rate, not “deterrent” effects. Even more important than this point of nomenclature are the implications of alternative possible mechanisms for using empirical findings on the death penalty effects to predict effects on the crime rate of alternative sanction regimes. As we discuss below, alternative mechanisms can imply very different inferences and interpretations. We emphasize this point because the issue of mechanisms is one of several reasons that inferences about the causal effect of capital punishment on homicide rates cannot be reduced to a simple statistical exercise:

the validity of the inferences also depend on the validity of the theories used to construct the statistical models that generate the estimated effects.

The mechanism by which capital punishment might affect homicide rates also has implications for the time frame over which the effect operates. The socialization processes about which Andenæs (1974) and Packer (1968) speculate would likely take years or even decades to materialize and if present would probably operate gradually. Gradual change over long time frames, even if cumulatively large, is often extremely difficult to measure convincingly.

Another issue related to time frame, to which we return in the conclusions of this report, is the processes by which perceptions of sanction risk are formed and are influenced by changes in sanction policy. For example, immediately following the Gregg decision, 33 states had capital punishment statutes in place (see Chapter 2 ). Individual states subsequently followed very different paths in the frequency, relative to the murder rate, with which death penalties were imposed and carried out. If would-be murderers are responsive to this relative frequency, it would take time for them to calibrate the intensity in the state in which they reside and to recognize any changes in intensity resulting from policy shifts. Thus, any effect on homicide rates of changes in the frequency of execution may not occur until after some unknown interval.

The remainder of this chapter lays out key challenges to estimating the causal effect of capital punishment on murder rates. Many of these challenges stem from the necessity of using nonexperimental data to estimate this effect. A useful way of conceptualizing these challenges is to note the important differences between data generated from experiments and data generated under nonexperimental conditions. In an experiment, the effectiveness of a treatment is tested by administering the treatment to a randomly selected group of subjects and comparing their outcomes to another group of randomly selected subjects who receive the control treatment. Randomization of treatment status is intended to ensure the equivalence of the treatment and control groups except for treatment status. The purpose of an experiment is to measure the effect of a specified treatment on one or more outcomes relative to an alternative treatment, generally referred to as the control treatment. Experiments are a widely accepted way of scientifically testing for causal effects: there is general agreement that the findings are reflective of causal effects.

For obvious reasons, it is not possible to conduct a randomized capital punishment experiment. Suppose, however, that such an experiment were possible. In such an experiment, three key features would be relevant: (1) specification of what constitutes treatment, (2) randomization of the capital punishment treatment, and (3) experimental control of the treatment. In addition, in an experiment, the experimental and control treatment al-

ternatives must be specified prior to the beginning of the experiment, and treatment status is controlled by the experimenter, not the subjects of the experiment. We develop below the implications of each of the features of experiments for the study of the effect of capital punishment with nonexperimental data.

SANCTION REGIMES

A sanction regime defines the way a jurisdiction administers a sanction. In an experiment, the differences between the sanction regimes in the treatment and control jurisdictions would define what constitutes treatment. In a capital punishment jurisdiction, specification of the sanction regime would require a delineation of the types of crimes and offenders that would be eligible for capital punishment and the rules that would be used to determine whether an eligible offender could be sentenced to death. It would also require a specification of the appeals and pardon processes. In addition, sanctions for individuals not sentenced to death would have to be specified. The sanction regime in a jurisdiction without capital punishment would have to be similarly specified. Such an experiment, therefore, would not test the efficacy of “capital punishment” in the abstract. Instead, it would test a particular capital punishment against a specific alternative regime without capital punishment. Only after specification and assignment of the capital and noncapital sanction regimes could the experiment begin and the data collected.

By contrast, in studies based on nonexperimental data, sanction regimes are not specified and assigned prior to data collection. Instead, the researcher has to make assumptions about the theoretically relevant dimensions of the sanction regimes of the entities administering the punishment, usually states. Thus, a key question in an assessment of the validity of a capital punishment study involves those assumptions: How convincingly does a study specify and explain aspects of the capital punishment sanction regime it is studying?

The legal status of the death penalty in the jurisdiction is one relevant dimension of a sanction regime. States with and without the death penalty have clearly defined differences in their sanction regimes. However, the numerous differences across states in the types of offenses that are capital eligible and the administrative processes related to the imposition and appeal of the death sentences (as described in Chapter 2 ) may be relevant to defining aspects of the sanction regime that have the potential to influence deterrence. For example, Frakes and Harding (2009) attempt to examine whether the explicit delineation of the killing of a child as an aggravating circumstance for the use of the death penalty deters child murder. Still another important dimension of the sanction regime is the severity of non-

capital sanctions for murder in both capital and noncapital punishment states, a point we return to below.

A sanction regime is also defined by how aggressively the authority to use the death penalty is actually applied. Among states that provide authority for the use of the death penalty, the frequency with which that authority is used varies greatly. As pointed out in Chapter 2 , since 1976 three states—Florida, Texas, and Virginia—have accounted for more than one-half of all executions carried out in the United States, even though 40 states and the federal government provided the legal authority for the death penalty for at least part of this period. Constructing measures of the intensity with which capital punishment is used in states with that authority is a particularly daunting problem. In an experiment, the intensity of application would have to be specified ex ante by delineating the circumstances in which capital punishment should be applied. With nonexperimental data, intensity must be inferred ex post by the rate of application. The panel studies calculate intensity by an assortment of measures of the probability of execution based on variations over time and among states in the frequency of executions to distinguish, for example, the very different sanction regimes of Texas and California. Chapter 4 discusses these measures at length.

The concept of deterrence predicts that one relevant dimension of a sanction regime is the probability of execution given conviction for a capital eligible murder. However, if deterrence is predicated on the perception of the risk of execution, short-term or even longer term variations in the rate of executions may not produce changes in the homicide rate, even if the death penalty is a deterrent. If such temporal variation in the actual rate of administration is perceived as confirming stable perceptions about this probability, rather than signaling change in the probability, such variations will not be associated with changes in the homicide rate even though the intensity of the use of capital punishment does deter.

An example from gambling on the outcome of the role of a dice can illustrate this point. Suppose a person knows that the dice are fair. For that person, the actual outcomes of successive roles of the dice will not cause the person to change the estimate that the chance of each number is 1/6. Therefore, that person’s betting patterns will not change in response to short-term variations in the frequency of each of the numbers 1 to 6. The analog for deterrence research is that variations over time in the actual frequency of executions may not alter would-be murderers perceptions of the risk of execution and therefore not alter behavior even if there is a deterrent effect.

However, it is possible that perceptions are influenced by the actual outcomes. If so, a bettor’s betting pattern would change in response to the outcomes of the dice rolls. But if this is the case, it is necessary to posit a specific model of how those perceptions change to infer how behavior changes. For example, the so-called gambler’s fallacy (Gilovich, 1983) pos-

its that if one number, say 6, is rolled several times in a row, people will surmise that the probability of a 6 is reduced at least temporarily and thus reduce their betting on 6. In the context of deterrence, the gambler’s fallacy model suggests that the event of an execution might increase, not decrease, murders because people will surmise that the probability of execution has declined at least temporarily. Alternatively, people may surmise that the dice is weighted to favor 6 and therefore increase their betting on 6. Under this model, the event of an execution might cause individuals to increase their perception of the risk of execution and thereby reduce the murder rate. We do not specifically endorse any of these models of risk perception. Our purpose in this discussion is to emphasize that in the analysis of nonexperimental data, the sanction regime must be constructed ex post on the basis of the researcher’s assumptions about theoretically relevant constructs. In turn, this fact implies that the relevant dimensions of a sanction regime cannot be specified outside of a model of sanction risk perceptions and their effect on behavior.

It is a truism that sanction threats cannot deter unless at least some would-be offenders are aware of the threat. There is a large literature on sanction risk perceptions that demonstrates that the general public is very poorly informed about actual sanction levels and the frequency of their imposition (Apel, in press). These studies might be interpreted as demonstrating that legal sanctions cannot deter (since people do not really know what they are). This interpretation neglects the possibility that some would-be offenders may be deterred by the mere knowledge that there is a criminal sanction even if the severity of the sanction is not specifically known to them. Moreover, most people do not commit crimes for a host of reasons that are unrelated to the certainty and severity of criminal sanctions. These people have no reason to know, for example, the frequency with which executions are carried out, because they have no intention of committing murder. Some degree of deterrence only requires that some people who are actively considering committing a crime are aware of the penalties and that their behavior is influenced by this awareness.

Still, as the dice example illustrates, the issue of how the death penalty sanction is perceived is fundamental to the interpretation of the evidence on its deterrent effect. Consider an actual, not hypothetical, example. Donohue and Wolfers (2005) compared trends in homicide rates between states with and without capital punishment from 1960 to 2000, a period that spans the 1972 Furman decision that stopped use of the death penalty and 1976 Gregg decision that reinstated it. The time-series data for the two states closely track each other, with no obvious perturbations at the time of the Furman and Gregg decisions. From these data one could conclude there is no obvious evidence that the moratorium on capital punishment or its reinstatement had an effect on murder rates. However, because the last ex-

ecution prior to the Furman decision was in 1967 and executions were rare throughout the 1960s, there are two very different possible interpretations of the data. One interpretation is that the deterrent effect of the potential for a death sentence is small or nonexistent. The other is that the near absence of executions in the decade prior to Furman resulted in people’s stable perceptions in both abolitionist and nonabolitionist states that there was no realistic chance of the death penalty being imposed. With such perceptions there would be no possibility of a deterrent effect even if would-be murderers would otherwise be deterred by the threat of execution.

The issue of how sanction threats are perceived is also important in correctly interpreting evidence that is taken as reflecting deterrence. For example, some time-series studies report evidence that suggests reduced homicides in the immediate aftermath of an execution. Suppose this is, in fact, a reflection of a causal effect of an execution on murder. Depending on how the threat of execution is perceived, there are a number of very different interpretations of this evidence. One possible model of perceptions is that people respond to the event of an execution, with each execution reducing the number of murders that would otherwise occur according to a dose-response relationship relating murders averted to number of executions in a given time frame. A second model is that people respond not to the event of an execution but to the perceived probability of execution given commission of a murder, and that the event of an execution causes them to update this perceived probability. In this model, the number of both executions and murders is relevant to the updating process. Unlike the first model, there is no single dose-response relationship between number of executions and murders. If the frequency of execution does not keep pace with the rate of increase in murders, would-be murderers might infer that the probability of execution is declining. Yet a third model of such time-series evidence is that the event of an execution only alters the timing of the murder—a murder averted in the immediate aftermath of an execution occurs at a later date. We do not endorse any of these interpretations: we offer them to make concrete the proposition that the interpretation of evidence requires a model of sanction risk perceptions and of the effect of those perceptions on behavior. 2

2 We also emphasize that this same observation about the need for a model of sanction risk perceptions and their influence on behavior applies to the interpretation of evidence from an experiment. Only in an impossibly idealized experiment would it be possible to specify the sanction regime in such detail to avoid the need to extrapolate from the experimental findings to explain their implications for unspecified aspects of the sanction regime. Furthermore, even with a completely specified sanction regime, extrapolation of the findings to other settings or modified versions of the tested sanction regime would require a theory of perceptions and behavior.

DATA ISSUES

In any empirical study it is important to question the adequacy of the data used in the analysis. In the context of the studies reviewed for this report a key question is whether the data being used are adequate to produce credible estimates of the effects of those aspects of the sanction regime under investigation.

As noted above, most studies of the deterrent effect of capital punishment are based on U.S. data. Although the U.S. data on murder show far less underreporting than data on other types of crime, the data on murders contain flaws that are important to recognize in studies on deterrence. The murder rates used in most studies include murders that are not eligible for capital punishment, either because of characteristics of the perpetrator (such as age or IQ) or because of characteristics of the offense (such as the absence of legally defined aggravating factors). The supplemental homicide reports, a dataset compiled by the Federal Bureau of Investigation (FBI) that provides more detailed data on homicide incidents than the agency’s standardized Uniform Crime Report , in principle provide details of the perpetrator and the event that allow researchers to exclude murders that likely are not eligible for capital punishment; but these data have their own set of problems due to widespread recording errors and omissions about characteristics of the perpetrator and the event itself (Messner, Deane, and Beaulieu, 2002; Wadsworth and Roberts, 2008).

As we emphasize above, the deterrent effect of capital punishment is a meaningful concept only relative to another key dimension of the sanction regime—the severity of noncapital sanctions. After all, as a practical question of public policy, the key question is not whether a hypothetical capital punishment regime in which execution is the only available sanction for murder would deter some offenders. Rather, it is whether a plausible capital punishment regime will have a meaningful incremental effect on homicide rates in the United States when added to a specific program of lesser sanctions. Hence, state-level data on alternative punishments are necessary, most specifically, the prison sentence lengths for murders that might also be candidates for capital punishment.

Such data do not exist. This gap is potentially a serious one for studying deterrence. If the severity of noncapital sanctions for murder is correlated with the legal status or the frequency of use of capital punishment, failure to account for the severity of noncapital sanctions may result in serious bias in estimates of deterrent effect. If, for example, capital punishment jurisdictions tended also to impose more severe imprisonment sanctions than noncapital jurisdictions, a reduced level of homicide in such jurisdictions may be attributable to these other features of their sanction regime and not to the death penalty. Or, if capital punishment jurisdictions are otherwise

more lenient, any deterrent effect achieved by adding capital punishment might not translate into a similar effect of adding capital punishment in a jurisdiction that already imposes severe prison sentences for murder. Or, if a state relied on the threat of capital punishment to counter an inadequate budget for investigating and prosecuting crimes, the deterrent effect of capital punishment might be masked relative to a noncapital punishment state with more effective crime control policy. Again, we do not endorse any of these hypotheses, but delineate them to illustrate the difficulty of isolating deterrent effects of a single component of any sanction regime.

VARIATIONS IN MURDER RATES

The severity of noncapital sanctions is but one example of other factors that may affect murder rates. If the data being analyzed were the product of a randomized capital punishment experiment, the question of how other factors influence murder rates would not have to be addressed. Randomization of the capital punishment sanction regime would insure that the use of capital punishment was uncorrelated with other factors influencing murder rates. Thus, for example, if a capital punishment sanction regime were randomized across states, capital punishment would not be more commonplace in the Southern states, as in practice it is. By breaking the correlation between treatment, in this case capital punishment, and other factors that may be influencing the outcome of interest, in this case murders, randomization ensures that the capital punishment deterrent effect estimate is not contaminated by the independent influence of these other factors on murder rates. Because capital punishment research is based on nonexperimental data, equivalence of states without and without capital punishment on all other factors is not insured. Hence, consideration of the influence of factors other than capital punishment on murder rates must be addressed.

Homicide rates in the United States vary enormously over time and place. In 2009, Louisiana had the highest statewide rate, 11.8 homicides per 100,000 population; the state with the lowest rate, New Hampshire, had 0.8 homicides per 100,000 population, 93 percent fewer (Bureau of Justice Statistics, 2010; Federal Bureau of Investigation, 2010). Variations over time are also large. Figure 3-1 plots the U.S. homicide rate over the 25-year period from 1974 to 2009. From 1974 to the early 1990s, the rate rose, then fell, then rose again, and then began declining steadily until leveling off in the early 2000s.

As we emphasize throughout this report, these variations are important to making a valid determination of the deterrent effect of the death penalty, because if other influences on the murder rate are correlated with the use of the death penalty, the estimated deterrent effect may be contaminated by the effect of these other influences on the homicide rates. Such other

image

FIGURE 3-1 Homicide rates in the United States: 1974 to 2009. SOURCES: Data from Bureau of Justice Statistics (2010) and Federal Bureau of Investigation (2010).

influences may reflect factors related to the criminal justice system. One has already been described: the severity of noncapital sanctions. Another is police effectiveness in apprehending murderers. If the probability of apprehension is correlated with the imposition of the death penalty, a finding that the death penalty seemingly deters murders might actually reflect police effectiveness in deterring murder. Such contamination may also come from social, economic, or political factors that affect the homicide rate and that are outside the criminal justice system.

There have been numerous commentaries on the sources of variation in U.S. homicide rates, with many focusing specifically on the sharp drop in homicides since the early 1990s (Blumstein and Wallman, 2000, 2006; Levitt, 2004; Zimring, 2010; Zimring and Fagan, 2000). However, these commentaries provide very limited guidance on how to account for other possible sources of change in homicide rates in a statistical analysis of the deterrent effect of the death penalty.

To provide a concrete illustration of the challenges of inferring the deterrent effects of the death penalty, consider Texas, the state that makes the most frequent use of the death penalty (in absolute numbers). Figure 3-2 plots the annual frequency of executions in Texas from 1974 to 2009. Texas’s first post- Gregg execution occurred in 1982, and executions re-

image

FIGURE 3-2 Executions in Texas: 1974 to 2009. SOURCES: Data from Espy and Smykla (2004) and Texas Department of Criminal Justice (2011).

mained relatively infrequent until the early 1990s; the frequency then escalated rapidly to a peak of 40 in 2000. Thereafter, there has been drop-off to about 20-25 per year. Figure 3-3 plots the homicide rate in Texas (as well as California and New York) over the same period. The pattern for all three states closely resembles the U.S. national trend. From 1974 through the early 1990s the Texas homicide rate rose then fell and then rose again before falling steadily from 1991 to the early 2000s, when it leveled off. For the period from 1976 to 1991, there is no apparent relationship between the homicide rate and the frequency of execution. However, the steady decline in the homicide rate since 1991 does correspond with the dramatic increase in executions that occurred in the early 1990s. Thus, if the early 1990s is assumed to be the demarcation of Texas shifting to a dramatically higher use of capital punishment, the data are consistent with that shift having a deterrent effect.

However, the data from California and New York challenge that interpretation. The death penalty has been an available sentencing option in California for the entire post-1976 period, but the frequency of executions in California is low in comparison with Texas—from 1976 to 2009, California executed 13 people, and Texas executed 447. Both states, however, sentenced sizable numbers of people to death. In this regard, New York offers still another interesting contrast. It sentenced only 10 people to

image

FIGURE 3-3 Homicide rates in California, New York, and Texas: 1974 to 2009. SOURCES: Data from Bureau of Justice Statistics (2010) and Federal Bureau of Investigation (2010).

death between 1973 and 2009 and had executed none as of 2009 (Bureau of Justice Statistics, 2010). 3

As shown in Figure 3-3 , the California, New York, and Texas homicide rates move in close unison for the entire 1974-2009 period. Like Texas, the California and New York rates rise, then fall, and then rise between 1974 and the early 1990s; the rates for all three states then begin a steep decline to the early 2000s and level out. Thus, even though California, New York, and Texas have made very different use of the death penalty, particularly since 1990, their homicide rates are remarkably the same over about three decades.

Our purpose in reporting these data is not to draw any conclusion about the deterrent effect of the death penalty. The three states were purposely selected to illustrate the importance of accounting for variations, across time and place, in factors that influence murder rates other than the use of capital punishment. If informal comparisons of data from a few self-selected jurisdictions were sufficient to settle the question of the deterrent effect of the death penalty, the reviews of the panel studies in Chapter 4 and the of time-series studies in Chapter 5 , which are based on application of

3 In New York, the legal authority for the death penalty was available only from 1995 to 2007.

formal statistical methods, would be unnecessary. For example, the panel studies are based on data from all 50 states, not just three selected ones.

In addition, and most critically, any inferences about the effects of the death penalty that are based on the data reported in Figure 3-3 require a conception—that is, a plausible hypothesis—of how the death penalty might affect homicide rates. Suppose, as is assumed in some of the time-series studies reviewed in Chapter 5 , the residents of these three states respond to deviations away from their state’s long-term trend in executions or death sentences and not to the trend lines themselves. Informal inferences based on visual inspection of long-term homicide rates and death penalty sanction trends cannot provide the basis for detecting such relationships: in Chapter 5 we apply the formal statistical methods that can detect those relationship. More generally, if valid inferences about the effect of the death penalty on homicide rates could be drawn from superficial analysis of data plots like those in Figure 3-3 , the question of its effect would have been settled long ago. For the committee’s discussion of this point, see the section on cross-polity comparisons in Chapter 5 .

RECIPROCAL EFFECTS BETWEEN HOMICIDE RATES AND SANCTION REGIMES

In an experiment, one very important consequence of random assignment of treatment is that treatment assignment is not affected by the outcome of interest. For example, in a randomized experiment of the effectiveness of a therapy in reducing depression, the probability of participants receiving the experimental treatment is not influenced by their level of depression at the time of treatment assignment. As a consequence, the direction of causality is clear—any difference in symptoms of depression between the experimental and control groups is a consequence of the treatments assigned and not of the level of depression at the time of treatment. In analyses of nonexperimental data, attribution of direction of causality in an association between two variables is often far less clear.

Going back to deterrence research in the 1960s, there has been concern about the possibility that estimates of deterrent effects were biased by reciprocal effects between crime rates and sanction levels. That is, while sanction levels may be influencing crime rates through the processes of deterrence, crime rates may simultaneously be affecting sanction levels. Crime rates may influence sanctions by a variety of mechanisms. One possibility is that, in the short run, increases in crime may strain the resources committed to the criminal justice system and result in a reduction in overall effective sanction levels. Over the longer term, the political process might respond to rising crime rates by increasing the resources committed to crime control and increasing the severity of sanctions.

The possibility of reciprocal effects greatly complicates estimation of the deterrent effect of capital punishment. For example, suppose that states with high rates of executions (as measured by the percentage of homicides that result in executions) tend also to have lower homicide rates. One interpretation of this negative association is deterrence: that is, more certain application of the death penalty reduces murders. However, if there are reciprocal effects of crime rates on sanction levels, this negative association might just as well reflect the resource saturation effect noted above: that is, higher murder rates and crime rates tend to overwhelm the capacity of the justice system to respond to crime. Higher crimes rates may, for example, reduce the effectiveness of police in apprehending criminals or may make overburdened prosecutors more receptive to accepting plea bargains for noncapital sanctions in order to avoid trials. Both such mechanisms could contribute to reductions in the frequency of executions.

The possibility of reciprocal causation is not addressed in the time-series research, and only a subset of studies in the panel research make any attempt to address this very challenging problem. Given enough assumptions, it is possible to disentangle empirically causal effects in the presence of reciprocal causation. Thus, in principle, in the above example, the deterrent effect of execution certainty can be distinguished from the effect of murder rates on execution certainty. However, such analysis requires the imposition of what are called “identification restrictions.” Identification restrictions can come in many forms, and isolating the role of any one restriction is difficult and sometimes impossible.

In the panel studies in which reciprocal causation is addressed, an important component of identification involves the use of “instrumental variables.” Chapter 4 includes an extended discussion of the validity of the assumptions that underlie the instrumental variable applications in that research. Here we emphasize only that in the presence of reciprocal causation, estimation of causal effects ultimately depends on more than just the data. This is still another example of the fact that the validity of the estimates of the effects of deterrence depends significantly on modeling assumptions—in this case the plausibility of untestable assumptions about identification restrictions. This is not, by itself, a fatal criticism, since identification restrictions can often be derived from social science theories. However, not all assumptions are equally plausible, so their validity has to be judged in context.

The presence of reciprocal effects also complicates the interpretation of findings on the deterrent effect of the death penalty even if based on plausible identification restrictions. For example, suppose that a state changes its death penalty sanction regime by expanding the types of murders that are eligible for the death penalty and that this change has the desired deterrent effect, which is estimated, based on plausible identification restrictions, to

reduce the murder rate by 5 percent. In the presence of feedback effects, the ultimate reduction in the murder rate will not be 5 percent: it may be more or it may be less because the change in the murder rate may affect other aspects of the sanction regime, such as the way prosecutors and defense attorneys approach plea bargains or the resources available to the criminal justice system. These changes, in turn, may further influence the murder rate. Furthermore, the sentencing regime that caused the 5 percent reduction may differ from a regime without the death penalty, not just because of the possibility of a death sentence, but also because the availability of the death penalty as an option provides prosecutors with greater leverage in plea negotiations (which may result in a greater number of long prison sentences) and because the extra resources required to try capital cases may affect the resources available to prosecute and try other crimes.

In North Carolina, for example, 25 percent of first-degree murder cases are initially prosecuted capitally. Each of these cases requires relatively more resources because of extra care for due process. The in-kind costs include the equivalent of nine assistant prosecutors each year, as well as 345 days of trial court time, approximately 10 percent of the resources of the Supreme Court, and $11 million in cash outlays (Cook, 2009). Only after all these feedbacks have played themselves out could the ultimate effect of a change in sanction regime on the murder rate be determined. This kind of feedback is still another reason that throughout this report we describe empirical estimates of the effects of the death penalty as effects on the homicide rate, not as deterrent effects.

In this and the preceding chapter we lay out some of the key challenges to using data from the studies reviewed in the next two chapters to infer the causal effect of the death penalty on the homicide rate. Some of these challenges can be resolved empirically. For example, with data on the severity of noncapital sanctions, it is possible to test empirically whether the inclusion of these data in the analysis alters estimates of the causal effect of capital punishment on murder rates. More generally, it is also possible to analyze the sensitivity of findings to a specified set of alternative model specifications. We discuss examples of such tests in those chapters.

However, it is also important to recognize that inferences about the effect of alternative capital punishment regimes cannot be reduced to purely statistical questions. Interpretations will always depend on assumptions about the underlying mechanisms by which sanction regimes affect behavior and how behavior in turn affects sanction regimes and that those assumptions are not testable with the data used in the analysis. As a consequence, inferences about the effects of capital and noncapital sanction

regimes on murder rates will depend on more than the data that generate the estimates: the inferences will also depend on the validity of the theories used to construct the models on which the estimates rest.

Andenæs, J. (1974). Punishment and Deterrence . Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Apel, R. (in press). Sanctions, perceptions, and crime: Implications for criminal deterrence. Submitted to Journal of Quantitative Criminology, 28 .

Becker, G.S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76 (2), 169-217.

Blumstein, A., and Wallman, J. (2000). The Crime Drop in America . New York: Cambridge University Press.

Blumstein, A., and Wallman, J. (2006). The crime drop and beyond. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 2 (1), 125-146.

Braithwaite, J. (1989). Crime, Shame, and Reintegration . New York: Cambridge University Press.

Bureau of Justice Statistics. (2010). Capital Punishment, 2009—Statistical Tables . Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Justice. Available: http://bjs.ojp.usdoj.gov/index.cfm?ty=pbdetail&iid=2215 [December 2011].

Cook, P.J. (1980). Research in criminal deterrence: Laying the groundwork for the second decade. Crime and Justice, 2 , 211-268.

Cook, P.J. (1986). The relationship between victim resistance and injury in noncommercial robbery. Journal of Legal Studies, 15 (2), 405-416.

Cook, P.J. (2009). Potential savings from abolition of the death penalty in North Carolina. American Law and Economics Review, 11 (2), 498-529.

Donohue, J.J., and Wolfers, J. (2005). Uses and abuses of empirical evidence in the death penalty debate. Stanford Law Review, 58 (3), 791-845.

Durlauf, S., and Nagin, D. (2011). The deterrent effect of imprisonment. In P.J. Cook, J. Ludwig, and J. McCrary (Eds.), Controlling Crime: Strategies and Tradeoffs (pp. 43-94). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Espy, M.W., and Smykla, J.O. (2004). Executions in the United States, 1608-2002: The Espy File . Available: http://www.deathpenaltyinfo.org/executions-us-1608-2002-espy-file [December 2011].

Federal Bureau of Investigation. (2010). Crime in the United States 2009. Washington, DC: Author.

Frakes, M., and Harding, M.C. (2009). The deterrent effect of death penalty eligibility: Evidence from the adoption of child murder eligibility factors. American Law and Economics Review, 11 (2), 451-497.

Gilovich, T. (1983). Biased evaluation and persistence in gambling. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 44 (6), 1,110-1,126.

Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47 (2), 263-291.

Kleiman, M. (2009). When Brute Force Fails: How to Have Less Crime and Less Punishment . Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Levitt, S.D. (2004). Understanding why crime fell in the 1990s: Four factors that explain the decline and six that do not. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18 (1), 163-190.

Messner, S.F., Deane, G., and Beaulieu, M. (2002). A log-multiplicative association model for allocating homicides with unknown victim-offender relationships. Criminology, 40 (2), 457-480.

Nagin, D.S. (1998). Criminal deterrence research at the outset of the twenty-first century. Crime and Justice, 23 , 1-42.

Packer, H.L. (1968). The Limits of the Criminal Sanction . Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

Pogarsky, G. (2009). Deterrence and decision-making: Research questions and theoretical refinements. In M.D. Krohn, A. Lizotte and H.G. Penlly (Eds.), Handbook on Crime and Deviance (pp. 241-258). New York: Springer.

Texas Department of Criminal Justice. (2011). Executed Offenders . Available: http://www.tdcj.state.tx.us/death_row/dr_executed_offenders.html.

Wadsworth, T.I.M., and Roberts, J.M. (2008). When missing data are not missing: A new approach to evaluating supplemental homicide report imputation strategies. Criminology, 46 (4), 841-870.

Zimring, F.E. (2010). The scale of imprisonment in the United States: Twentieth century patterns and twenty-first century prospects. Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology, 100 (3), 1,225-1,246.

Zimring, F.E., and Fagan, J. (2000). The search for causes in an era of crime declines: Some lessons from the study of New York City homicide. Crime & Delinquency, 46 (4), 446-456.

This page intentionally left blank.

Many studies during the past few decades have sought to determine whether the death penalty has any deterrent effect on homicide rates. Researchers have reached widely varying, even contradictory, conclusions. Some studies have concluded that the threat of capital punishment deters murders, saving large numbers of lives; other studies have concluded that executions actually increase homicides; still others, that executions have no effect on murder rates. Commentary among researchers, advocates, and policymakers on the scientific validity of the findings has sometimes been acrimonious.

Against this backdrop, the National Research Council report Deterrence and the Death Penalty assesses whether the available evidence provides a scientific basis for answering questions of if and how the death penalty affects homicide rates. This new report from the Committee on Law and Justice concludes that research to date on the effect of capital punishment on homicide rates is not useful in determining whether the death penalty increases, decreases, or has no effect on these rates. The key question is whether capital punishment is less or more effective as a deterrent than alternative punishments, such as a life sentence without the possibility of parole. Yet none of the research that has been done accounted for the possible effect of noncapital punishments on homicide rates. The report recommends new avenues of research that may provide broader insight into any deterrent effects from both capital and noncapital punishments.

READ FREE ONLINE

Welcome to OpenBook!

You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

Show this book's table of contents , where you can jump to any chapter by name.

...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

Switch between the Original Pages , where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter .

Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

View our suggested citation for this chapter.

Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

Get Email Updates

Do you enjoy reading reports from the Academies online for free ? Sign up for email notifications and we'll let you know about new publications in your areas of interest when they're released.

Journal article

The 'Brutalization' Thesis (George L. Mosse) and its Critics: A Historiographical Debate

Angel Alcalde

PASADO Y MEMORIA-REVISTA DE HISTORIA CONTEMPORANEA | UNIV ALICANTE | Published : 2016

DOI: 10.14198/PASADO2016.15.01

This article explores the widespread international debate in modern historiography maintained around the “brutalization” thesis, which was popularized in George L. Mosse’s book Fallen Soldiers (1990). According to Mosse, the war experience of the front soldiers during World War I was the cause of the heightened levels of political violence during the Weimar Republic. Such brutalization allegedly provided the basis for Nazism and the Genocide. In an attempt to clarify the origins of Mosse’s interpretation this work analyses criticism, reformulations and uses of “brutalization”. In spite of the fact that the heated debate reached no consensus, it eventually managed to establish a revealing –th..

University of Melbourne Researchers

Citation metrics.

Deterrence Versus Brutalization: Capital Punishment's Differing Impacts Among States

Michigan Law Review, Forthcoming

Emory Law and Economics Research Paper No. 05-16

48 Pages Posted: 11 Aug 2005

Joanna M. Shepherd

Emory University School of Law

This paper is the first study to establish that capital punishment's impact is different among U.S. states, deterring murders in some states, but actually increasing murders in many others. Studies by economists, including myself, have typically used large data sets of all 50 states or all U.S. counties to show that executions, on average, deter murders. In contrast, studies by sociologists, criminologists, and law professors often examine only one or a few jurisdictions and usually find no evidence of deterrence. Using a well-known data set and well-tested empirical methods, I find that the impact of executions differs substantially among the states. Executions deter murders in six states and have no effect on murders in eight states. In thirteen states, executions increase murders - what I call the "brutalization effect." In general, the states that have executed more than nine people in the last twenty years experience deterrence. In states that have not reached this threshold, executions generally increase murders or have no significant impact. On average across the U.S., executions deter crime because the states with deterrence execute many more people than do the states without it. The results of this paper help to explain the contrasting conclusions of earlier papers: whether deterrence exists depends on which states are examined. My results have three important policy implications. First, if deterrence is the objective, then capital punishment generally succeeds in the few states with many executions. Second, the many states with numbers of executions below the threshold may be executing people needlessly. Indeed, instead of deterring crime, the executions may be inducing additional murders: a rough total estimate is that, in the many states where executions induce murders rather than deter them, executions cause an additional 250 murders per year. Third, to achieve deterrence, states must generally execute many people. If a state is unwilling to establish such a large execution program, it should consider abandoning capital punishment.

Keywords: death penalty, deterrence, capital punishment

JEL Classification: K00, K14, K42, H00, C00, C33

Suggested Citation: Suggested Citation

Joanna M. Shepherd (Contact Author)

Emory university school of law ( email ).

1301 Clifton Road Atlanta, GA 30322 United States 404-727-8957 (Phone)

Do you have a job opening that you would like to promote on SSRN?

Paper statistics, related ejournals, emory university school of law legal studies research paper series.

Subscribe to this free journal for more curated articles on this topic

Law & Economics eJournal

Subscribe to this fee journal for more curated articles on this topic

Recommended Papers

The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: A Question of Life and Death

By Isaac Ehrlich

Capital Punishment and Deterrence: Some Further Thoughts and Additional Evidence

Uses and Abuses of Empirical Evidence in the Death Penalty Debate

By John J. Donohue and Justin Wolfers

By Justin Wolfers and John J. Donohue

Does Capital Punishment Have a Deterrent Effect? New Evidence from Post-Moratorium Panel Data

By Hashem Dezhbakhsh , Paul H. Rubin , ...

Shooting Down the More Guns, Less Crime Hypothesis

By Ian Ayres and John J. Donohue

On the Issue of Causality in the Economic Model of Crime and Law Enforcement: Some Theoretical Considerations and Experimental Evidence

By Isaac Ehrlich and George Brower

  • Search Menu

Sign in through your institution

  • Advance articles
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • Why Submit?
  • About Social Forces
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic
  • < Previous

The Brutalization Effect: Execution Publicity and the Incidence of Homicide in South Carolina

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

David R. King, The Brutalization Effect: Execution Publicity and the Incidence of Homicide in South Carolina, Social Forces , Volume 57, Issue 2, December 1978, Pages 683–687, https://doi.org/10.1093/sf/57.2.683

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

In this note we report the results of a study of the effects of execution publicity on the incidence of homicide in a single State, South Carolina. The basic purpose is to see whether the data are consistent with the brutalization hypothesis; the use of the death penalty as a punishment by the state deadens people's respect for life and thus increases the incidence of homicide.

Personal account

  • Sign in with email/username & password
  • Get email alerts
  • Save searches
  • Purchase content
  • Activate your purchase/trial code
  • Add your ORCID iD

Institutional access

Sign in with a library card.

  • Sign in with username/password
  • Recommend to your librarian
  • Institutional account management
  • Get help with access

Access to content on Oxford Academic is often provided through institutional subscriptions and purchases. If you are a member of an institution with an active account, you may be able to access content in one of the following ways:

IP based access

Typically, access is provided across an institutional network to a range of IP addresses. This authentication occurs automatically, and it is not possible to sign out of an IP authenticated account.

Choose this option to get remote access when outside your institution. Shibboleth/Open Athens technology is used to provide single sign-on between your institution’s website and Oxford Academic.

  • Click Sign in through your institution.
  • Select your institution from the list provided, which will take you to your institution's website to sign in.
  • When on the institution site, please use the credentials provided by your institution. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.
  • Following successful sign in, you will be returned to Oxford Academic.

If your institution is not listed or you cannot sign in to your institution’s website, please contact your librarian or administrator.

Enter your library card number to sign in. If you cannot sign in, please contact your librarian.

Society Members

Society member access to a journal is achieved in one of the following ways:

Sign in through society site

Many societies offer single sign-on between the society website and Oxford Academic. If you see ‘Sign in through society site’ in the sign in pane within a journal:

  • Click Sign in through society site.
  • When on the society site, please use the credentials provided by that society. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.

If you do not have a society account or have forgotten your username or password, please contact your society.

Sign in using a personal account

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members. See below.

A personal account can be used to get email alerts, save searches, purchase content, and activate subscriptions.

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members.

Viewing your signed in accounts

Click the account icon in the top right to:

  • View your signed in personal account and access account management features.
  • View the institutional accounts that are providing access.

Signed in but can't access content

Oxford Academic is home to a wide variety of products. The institutional subscription may not cover the content that you are trying to access. If you believe you should have access to that content, please contact your librarian.

For librarians and administrators, your personal account also provides access to institutional account management. Here you will find options to view and activate subscriptions, manage institutional settings and access options, access usage statistics, and more.

Short-term Access

To purchase short-term access, please sign in to your personal account above.

Don't already have a personal account? Register

Month: Total Views:
December 2016 6
January 2017 2
February 2017 3
March 2017 2
April 2017 9
September 2017 2
October 2017 1
November 2017 6
January 2018 7
February 2018 2
March 2018 17
July 2018 1
October 2018 7
November 2018 5
December 2018 4
January 2019 2
March 2019 3
April 2019 3
May 2019 5
June 2019 2
August 2019 1
October 2019 1
November 2019 3
December 2019 8
January 2020 1
February 2020 3
March 2020 1
August 2020 5
September 2020 10
October 2020 5
November 2020 2
January 2021 14
February 2021 1
April 2021 5
June 2021 2
September 2021 6
October 2021 2
November 2021 1
January 2022 4
February 2022 11
September 2022 1
November 2022 1
February 2023 3
March 2023 8
April 2023 2
November 2023 1
February 2024 2
March 2024 1
April 2024 2

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Recommend to your Library

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1534-7605
  • Print ISSN 0037-7732
  • Copyright © 2024 University of North Carolina Chapel Hill
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Rights and permissions
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

  • Advanced search

Journal of the American Academy of Psychiatry and the Law

Advanced Search

The Creation of Dangerous Violent Criminals, Second Edition

  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • Info & Metrics
  • violentization process

The Creation of Dangerous Violent Criminals, Second Edition , is an introduction to the violentization process, a term coined by Dr. Athens, a professor of criminal justice who witnessed violence in his own childhood and adolescence. 1 In describing the violentization process, he offers a framework to explain how a person in a highly civilized society becomes a dangerous violent criminal through the completion of four social experiential stages that begin in the early stages of life. The author describes how this violentization process gradually transforms a frightened and angry child, more deserving of sympathy than antipathy, into one who commits heinous acts.

The book begins with several cases of monstrous acts by dangerous violent criminals, quickly raising questions of how people can commit such crimes. The author sets out to answer these questions by conducting in-depth interviews of incarcerated dangerous violent criminals, defined as those who committed heinous acts with little or no provocation. Dr. Athens approached this study with three assumptions. First, people are what they are as a result of social experiences. Second, significant experiences that create dangerous violent criminals occur gradually. Third, it is better to conduct an in-depth study of 50 people than to study 5,000 superficially. In applying this strategy, he focused on the common yet significant social experiences of confirmed and incipient violent criminals. In doing so, the author provides a solid case for his theory that it was these social experiences, rather than social environments or biophysiology, that best explain how benign individuals were transformed to dangerous violent criminals.

The majority of the book focuses on describing and providing case examples of four stages of significant experiences common to dangerous violent criminals. The first stage, brutalization, requires three elemental experiences: violent subjugation, personal horrification, and violent coaching, most of which occur in the home environment. Each experience involves a person undergoing coarse and cruel treatment from others, which results in a lasting and dramatic impact on the remainder of that person's life. According to the violentization process theory, one must undergo all three experiences to complete the brutalization stage, which usually happens by early adolescence.

The author describes the second stage of the violentization process as belligerency, which occurs when individuals consider what they must do to prevent themselves from experiencing additional brutalization. They conclude that they must begin taking violent action against others who unduly provoke them. The belligerency stage ends when the subject firmly resolves to resort to violence when necessary.

Violent performance constitutes the third stage of the violentization process. At the end of the belligerent stage, the subject awaits circumstances to test the newly developed resolve to physically attack provokers with the intention of causing serious injury. The provocation must be at least moderate for this person to attack. If the violent performer succeeds in the performance of violence, the resolution to take violent action then deepens.

Of particular value in understanding this violentization process is the fourth state, virulency, when subjects become aware that others' opinions have suddenly and drastically changed as a result of their violent performance. Subjects experience notoriety, and people act cautiously around them. The subject often feels invincible and decides to perform even more impressive violent acts. This individual is now a dangerous violent criminal who has resolved to grievously harm others, even with little or no provocation. Once an individual has completed all four stages, the likelihood of reformation is minimal.

Finally, this book discusses theoretical and policy implications of this framework, focusing on efforts that could halt the violentization process and prevent the creation of dangerous violent criminals. The author suggests that if society fails to aid in thwarting such transformations, it tacitly serves as an accomplice in creating them. Although the task of developing policy and strategies to prevent the creation of dangerous violent criminals is fraught with challenges, the discussion provided in this book serves as a springboard for additional forums on specific interventions that could prevent the violentization process.

Prior to chapter one, the author provides an “Introduction to the Transaction Edition” in which he reveals that he has added a fifth stage to his violentization process theory, violent predation, and has also renamed other stages of the violentization process and added elemental experiences. While none of these developments are covered in the chapters of the book, the author describes violent predation here as a stage when “the subject's violence level becomes totally unbounded, exceeding the outer limits of humanity” (Ref. 2 , p xv). It is unfortunate for the reader that the author's refinements to his theory are not incorporated into the chapters of his book.

This book provides a framework to view some forensic psychiatric patients and may be helpful in formulating concerns related to ongoing violence risk. Forensic psychiatrists would find the book a valuable read. It provides a well-written explanation of theviolentization process, which has been referenced and studied extensively. In general, this book is an easy read, with the chapters describing theory and policy implications being more tedious. Strengths of the book include its detailed case examples and in-depth explanations of each violentization stage. Critics have proposed weaknesses in the violentization process theory, claiming that it does not account for all dangerous violent criminals. 2 Regardless, Dr. Athens' work constitutes an important contribution to the field of criminology.

Disclosures of financial or other potential conflicts of interest: None.

  • © 2020 American Academy of Psychiatry and the Law
  • O'Donnell I

In this issue

  • Table of Contents
  • Index by author

Thank you for your interest in recommending The Journal of the American Academy of Psychiatry and the Law site.

NOTE: We only request your email address so that the person you are recommending the page to knows that you wanted them to see it, and that it is not junk mail. We do not capture any email address.

Citation Manager Formats

  • EndNote (tagged)
  • EndNote 8 (xml)
  • RefWorks Tagged
  • Ref Manager

del.icio.us logo

  • Tweet Widget
  • Facebook Like
  • Google Plus One

Jump to section

Related articles, cited by..., more in this toc section.

  • Unthinkable; Trauma, Truth, and the Trials of American Democracy
  • Criminal Testimonial Injustice
  • Baby Reindeer Review: The Interwoven Psyches of a “Stalker” and Her Prey

Similar Articles

Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.

To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to  upgrade your browser .

Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.

  • We're Hiring!
  • Help Center

paper cover thumbnail

Deterrence and brutalization: The dual effects of executions

Profile image of John Cochran

Related Papers

John Cochran

O n September 10, 1990 Charles Troy Coleman was put to death by lethal injection at the Oklahoma State Penitentiary. Coleman's execution was the first in the state in more than 25 years, generating significant media coverage and providing a unique opportunity to assess the impact of the state's return to executing capital offenders. Interrupted time-series analyses are performed with weekly data from the UCR Supplemental Homicide Reports for the state for the period January I989 through December 1991. Analyses are performed for the total level of criminal homicides and homicides disaggregated into two types of murder-felony murder and stranger homicides-testing hypotheses that predict opposing impacts for each type of homicide. A s predicted, no evidence of a deterrent or a brutalization effect is found for criminal homicides in general. Similarly, the predicted deterrent effect of the execution on the level of felony murders is not observed. Evidence of the predicted brutalization effect on the level of stranger homicides is observed, however. Supplementary analyses on further offense disag-gregations continue to support these initial findings and permit a more coherent interpretation of the results.

define brutalization hypothesis

The Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology (1973-)

Stewart D’Alessio , Lisa Stolzenberg

Zoltan J. Toth

Travis Pratt

Criminology & Public Policy

Denise Boots

Criminology

Carlisle Moody

Crime & Delinquency

Lisa Stolzenberg , Stewart D’Alessio

ABSTRACT American criminological theory and research has traditionally focused on individual offenders. Beginning in the 1970s, however, macro-level (or “ecological”) theory and research emerged (or “re-emerged”) and has since earned sustained criminological attention.

Homicide Studies

Christopher Lowenkamp

Loading Preview

Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.

RELATED PAPERS

Michael Donovan

John Stogner

Justice Quarterly

Craig Hemmens

SSRN Electronic Journal

Adrian Vermeule

Crime & Just.

Journal of Criminal Justice and Popular Culture

Karen Miller

Aaron Chalfin

Alan Clarke

Md. mohiminul islam himo

EBE, THOMAS

Sheldon Booyens

Kilanko Omololu

Claudio Giusti

Richard Lempert

Celestine Kahng

Southwest Journal of …

Stacy Mallicoat

Laura Dugan

The Social Science Journal

Metaphilosophy

Rosalind Simson

Robert J Kaminski

Wayne Shelley

New Criminal Law Review: An International and Interdisciplinary Journal

Eric Blumenson

Scott Phillips

Alan Villarante

Tomislav Kovandzic

Journal of Criminal Justice

Katherine van Wormer

Journal of Social Issues

Phoebe Ellsworth

Pauline Tracy Batiles

Journal of Quantitative Criminology

Andrew Myer

Corrections, edited by W. Chambliss and J. Golson.

William R Wood

Samuel A Bassey

RELATED TOPICS

  •   We're Hiring!
  •   Help Center
  • Find new research papers in:
  • Health Sciences
  • Earth Sciences
  • Cognitive Science
  • Mathematics
  • Computer Science
  • Academia ©2024

Brutalization

Criminology term: brutalization.

Brutalization is the perplexing process in which an individual who has been subjected to violence, trauma , or other forms of mistreatment becomes more prone to engaging in violent behavior. The brutalization hypothesis posits that exposure to violence and trauma can have a numbing effect on individuals, leading them to view violence as a normal or acceptable way of resolving conflicts. This can increase the likelihood of engaging in violent behavior, especially if other risk factors such as poverty, social isolation, or substance abuse are also present. The brutalization theory has been applied to various criminal behaviors, such as domestic violence, gang violence, and acts of terrorism. It indicates that curbing violent behavior necessitates not only the punishment of offenders but also the identification and remediation of underlying factors that may contribute to violent behavior. These factors include exposure to violence and trauma, social and economic inequality, and limited access to resources and support services. Therefore, interventions aimed at reducing violent behavior should encompass a comprehensive approach that considers both individual and societal factors. Addressing brutalization is an ongoing challenge that demands multifaceted strategies. In addition to providing access to support services, prevention programs may incorporate public education efforts that increase awareness of the risks associated with violence and trauma. By educating the public about the dangers of violent behavior and addressing underlying issues that contribute to it, society can work towards mitigating the brutalization process and reducing violent behavior.

define brutalization hypothesis

May 10, 2023

define brutalization hypothesis

Proofread by

Diya Sarker

Learn more terms, misdemeanor.

A misdemeanor is a type of criminal offense that falls between an infraction and a felony in terms of severity. These types of crimes are generally...

Retribution

In criminology, retribution is a fundamental concept in the philosophy of punishment that emphasizes the notion of just deserts. It is the idea that...

Species Justice

Species justice is a concept within the field of criminology that underscores the need for fairness, equity, and ethical treatment in the...

Spatial Criminology

Spatial criminology is a specialized subfield within criminology that focuses on the spatial dimensions of crime and criminal behavior. It involves...

U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government, Department of Justice.

Here's how you know

Official websites use .gov A .gov website belongs to an official government organization in the United States.

Secure .gov websites use HTTPS A lock ( Lock A locked padlock ) or https:// means you’ve safely connected to the .gov website. Share sensitive information only on official, secure websites.

NCJRS Virtual Library

Brutalization effect - execution publicity and the incidence of homicide in south carolina, additional details.

Box 2288 , Chapel Hill , NC 27515-2288 , United States

No download available

Availability, related topics.

IMAGES

  1. PPT

    define brutalization hypothesis

  2. PPT

    define brutalization hypothesis

  3. (PDF) Deterrence or Brutalization: What Is the Effect of Executions?

    define brutalization hypothesis

  4. Brutalization Meaning

    define brutalization hypothesis

  5. Brutalism (Theory in Forms)

    define brutalization hypothesis

  6. PPT

    define brutalization hypothesis

VIDEO

  1. proofs exist only in mathematics

  2. Hypothesis Testing

  3. wobble hypothesis @Harun-biozone

  4. Lesson1: Introduction to two sample test of hypothesis- Hove Kudakwashe

  5. Hypothesis Testing Theory

  6. 'Brutalization' Meaning and Pronunciation

COMMENTS

  1. Brutalization

    Brutalization. In criminology, brutalization refers to a hypothesized cause-and-effect relationship between executions and an increase in the homicide rate. This hypothesis proposes this relationship occurs because executions diminish the public's respect for life. Such an effect represents the opposite of a deterrent effect.

  2. Deterrence, Brutalization, and The Death Penalty: Another Examination

    Moreover, a multivariate autoregressive analysis, which includes measures of the frequency of executions, the level of print media attention devoted to executions, and selected sociodemographic variables, produced results consistent with the brutalization hypothesis for total homicides, as well as a variety of different types of killing ...

  3. Deterrence and the Death Penalty

    Alternatively, the brutalization hypothesis predicts the opposite effect. Given these possible and unknown underlying mechanisms, in the remainder of this report we discuss empirical estimates of the effects of the death on the homicide rate, not "deterrent" effects.

  4. The 'Brutalization' Thesis (George L. Mosse) and its Critics: A

    Such brutalization allegedly provided the basis for Nazism and the Genocide. In an attempt to clarify the origins of Mosse's interpretation this work analyses criticism, reformulations and uses of "brutalization". In spite of the fact that the heated debate reached no consensus, it eventually managed to establish a revealing -th..

  5. Deterrence Versus Brutalization: The Case of Arizona

    The rise of brutalization theory, and the growing evidence in support of the theory, poses a dilemma with a different significance: It appears that executions cause more homicides than they prevent and thus increase homicide rates. This study of deterrent and brutalization effects of an Arizona execution partially replicates and extends a study ...

  6. Deterrence or Brutalization: What Is the Effect of Executions?

    The two cases with mixed results favor the brutalization argument if the homi cide rates for the contiguous states are averaged. In the one case that is fully consistent with the deterrence argument, one of the two comparisons with contiguous nonchange states is very close (Kansas versus Missouri).

  7. Deterrence Versus Brutalization: Capital Punishment's Differing ...

    In thirteen states, executions increase murders - what I call the "brutalization effect." In general, the states that have executed more than nine people in the last twenty years experience deterrence.

  8. Brutalization and the Civilizing Process: An Ongoing Debate Between

    The objective of this article is to compare the concept of brutalization, analyzed by George Mosse, with the civilizing process, described by Norbert Elias. The intellectual life of these German-Jewish scholars will be reconstructed through the study of their relationships and their similar life experience.

  9. Effect of Executions Is Brutalization, Not Deterrence (From Challenging

    Recent studies using monthly homicide data have provided more reliable statistical evidence of brutalization. Phillips' study, contrary to its original claims, should properly be counted among those studies finding statistically significant support for the brutalization hypothesis. 29 notes, 97 references. Additional Details Grant Number (s ...

  10. Deterrence and Brutalization: The Dual Effects of Executions

    In search for a causal mechanism explaining an increase in the homicide rates, scholars have identified the brutalization effect: An execution may send a signal to potential offenders that lethal ...

  11. PDF The Brutalization Effect: Execution Publicity and the Incidence of

    The data reported in this note do not support the hypothesis, although there is some indication that execution publicity may have a delayed brutalization effect in the month following the appear- ance of an execution story. It is also important to point out, that the data do not conform to the deterrance hypothesis either.

  12. The Brutalization Effect: Execution Publicity and the Incidence of

    The basic purpose is to see whether the data are consistent with the brutalization hypothesis; the use of the death penalty as a punishment by the state deadens people's respect for life and thus increases the incidence of homicide.

  13. Bloodbath and Brutalization: Public Opinion and the Death Penalty

    The developmental features of these symbolic attitudes and the weakening of societal restraints against violence in general suggest that a brutalization hypothesis which predicts a public acceptance of high levels of executions is more supportable than a bloodbath reaction hypothesis. 70 references.

  14. The Creation of Dangerous Violent Criminals, Second Edition

    The majority of the book focuses on describing and providing case examples of four stages of significant experiences common to dangerous violent criminals. The first stage, brutalization, requires three elemental experiences: violent subjugation, personal horrification, and violent coaching, most of which occur in the home environment.

  15. Capital punishment and the brutalization effect

    This study sought to determine if a brutalization effect existed in the capital punishment data. A literature review uncovered limited research regarding capital punishment, both in terms of the ...

  16. Deterrence or Brutalization

    The effect of executions has been to increase homicides, not to deter them. These findings represent a direct challenge to the constitutionality of the death penalty regarding its negative impact on the victims of homicides sparked by executions. Reviews of earlier studies on the brutalizing and deterrent effects of capital punishment are ...

  17. Deterrence and brutalization: The dual effects of executions

    Such is not the case with affronts among persons known to one another. Thus in this study we assess two hypotheses regarding the impact of highly publicized executions: (1) a deterrent effect on nonstranger felony-murders and (2) a brutalization effect on argument-based homicides among strangers.

  18. PDF Microsoft Word

    However, brutalization states have the fewest death row sentences, with no-effect states averaging slightly more than brutalization states. Mean comparison tests indicate that the average total number of execu-tions are statistically different between deterrent states and other states at the 5% level.

  19. Deterrence or Brutalization: What Is the Effect of Executions?

    Controls for time trends, seasonality, the effects of war, and adjustments for autocorrelation tend to confirm this finding. Such a "brutalizing" effect of executions is consistent with research ...

  20. Lonnie Athens revisited: The social construction of violence

    Critical analysis of a Athens's criminological theory of "Violentization" Discussion of the nature and etiology of aggression and violence Discussing literature and studies that analyze Athens's main hypothesis Implications for future research

  21. Brutalization

    What is Brutalization? Brutalization is the perplexing process in which an individual who has been subjected to violence, trauma, or other forms of mistreatment becomes more prone to engaging in violent behavior. The brutalization hypothesis posits that exposure to violence and trauma can have a numbing effect on individuals, leading them to view violence as a normal or acceptable way of ...

  22. Deterrence, Brutalization, and the Death Penalty: Another Examination

    This study extended the Cochran et al. study of Oklahoma homicides by considering important death penalty variables not considered in the earlier analysis (the levels of execution and media coverage of executions during 1989-91); examining the immediate (within the week) and possible delayed deterrent/ brutalization effects of the death penalty for the various types of murder; and ...

  23. BRUTALIZATION EFFECT

    THE EFFECTS OF EXECUTION PUBLICITY ON THE INCIDENCE OF HOMICIDE IN SOUTH CAROLINA ARE EXAMINED TO TEST THE BRUTALIZATION THEORY THAT THE DEATH PENALTY DECREASES RESPECT FOR LIFE AND THUS INCREASES HOMICIDES.